TutorChase logo
Login
AP Microeconomics Notes

2.2.4 Determinants of Supply

Supply in a market is influenced by several factors beyond the price of a good. These non-price determinants cause the entire supply curve to shift, either increasing or decreasing the quantity supplied at all price levels. Understanding these determinants is crucial for analyzing how markets respond to changes in production costs, technology, and other economic conditions.

Input prices

The cost of inputs, or factors of production, is one of the most significant influences on supply. Inputs include resources like labor, raw materials, machinery, energy, and capital used in the production process. When these costs change, firms adjust their supply decisions accordingly.

  • Decrease in input prices: If the price of a key input falls, producers can produce goods at a lower cost. This makes production more profitable at every price level, encouraging firms to supply more. As a result, the supply curve shifts to the right (increase in supply).

  • Increase in input prices: When input costs rise, production becomes more expensive. This reduces the profitability of producing goods, causing firms to supply less at each price level. Consequently, the supply curve shifts to the left (decrease in supply).

Real-world examples:

  • A decline in global oil prices lowers transportation and manufacturing costs for many industries. For example, lower oil prices reduce the cost of shipping goods, allowing businesses like Amazon or Walmart to supply more products at lower prices.

  • An increase in the cost of wheat and dairy can raise input costs for bakery businesses. If flour and milk become more expensive, bakeries may cut back on production, shifting the supply curve leftward.

Input prices directly affect the cost of production. When costs go down, profit margins rise, motivating firms to expand supply. Conversely, rising costs compress profits and discourage production.

Technology

Technology plays a transformative role in determining the level of supply in a market. Technological innovations typically lead to more efficient production methods, enabling firms to produce more output with the same or fewer inputs.

  • Improved technology: New tools, machinery, or software that make production faster or cheaper allow firms to increase supply. This results in a rightward shift of the supply curve.

  • Temporary disruption from new technology: Occasionally, adopting new technology can be expensive or create short-term confusion or training needs. In these rare cases, the supply curve may temporarily shift to the left.

Real-world examples:

  • The introduction of assembly line production by Henry Ford revolutionized the automobile industry. This innovation dramatically reduced the cost and time required to produce cars, increasing the supply of automobiles in the market.

  • In the agriculture sector, the use of GPS-guided tractors and automated irrigation systems allows farmers to plant and harvest crops more efficiently. This improves yields and leads to greater overall supply.

Technological change is often non-linear, meaning that a small innovation can cause a large shift in supply. For example, a breakthrough in battery storage technology might dramatically increase the supply of electric vehicles.

The price of goods that are related in production also affects supply. Related goods are classified as either substitutes in production or complements in production, depending on how they are produced together.

Substitutes in production

Substitutes in production are goods that can be produced using the same resources. Producers often have to choose how to allocate their resources (like land, labor, or machinery) between the two goods.

  • Price increase of a substitute: If the price of one good increases, producers may shift resources toward that more profitable good. This leads to a decrease in the supply of the other good, shifting its supply curve to the left.

  • Price decrease of a substitute: If the price of a substitute falls, producers may revert to producing the original good, increasing its supply and causing a rightward shift in the supply curve.

Example:

  • A farmer can grow either corn or soybeans on the same land. If corn becomes more profitable due to rising prices, the farmer may allocate more land to corn and less to soybeans. This reduces the supply of soybeans.

Complements in production

Complements in production are goods that are produced together. An increase in the production of one good automatically increases the supply of its complement.

  • Price increase of a complement: When the price of one good rises, production increases, leading to a greater supply of both that good and its complement. This causes the supply curve of the complement to shift to the right.

  • Price decrease of a complement: If the price of a complement falls, production of both goods may decrease, shifting the supply curve of the complement to the left.

Example:

  • In the meatpacking industry, leather is produced as a byproduct of beef. If beef prices rise and more cattle are processed, the supply of leather increases. The supply curve for leather shifts rightward, even though the price of leather itself hasn’t changed.

Producers are constantly responding to relative profitability between products. Understanding the relationship between goods is essential for predicting how a change in the price of one product will influence the supply of others.

Expectations of future prices

Producers make decisions based not only on current prices but also on what they expect prices to be in the future. These expectations influence current supply.

  • Higher expected future prices: If producers anticipate higher prices in the near future, they may reduce the amount of the good supplied now in order to sell more later at higher prices. This leads to a leftward shift in the current supply curve.

  • Lower expected future prices: If producers expect prices to fall, they may want to sell as much as possible now, which increases current supply and causes the supply curve to shift to the right.

Real-world examples:

  • Oil producers who anticipate a global price spike due to geopolitical conflict may hold back supply now to maximize revenue later.

  • Conversely, if a government announces future price controls or tariffs, wheat farmers may increase supply before the policy takes effect, fearing lower future returns.

Expectations can be influenced by economic forecasts, policy changes, natural events, and global market trends. The timing of supply decisions often reflects forward-looking behavior in competitive markets.

Number of sellers in the market

The total supply in a market depends on how many firms are producing and selling a particular good. Changes in the number of sellers affect the aggregate supply, even if the output of individual firms remains unchanged.

  • Increase in the number of sellers: More sellers in a market increase the total quantity supplied at every price level, shifting the supply curve to the right.

  • Decrease in the number of sellers: If firms exit the market due to low profits, regulations, or high input costs, the total market supply decreases, shifting the supply curve to the left.

Real-world examples:

  • A new wave of technology startups enters the market for mobile apps, increasing the number of available applications and shifting the supply curve for apps rightward.

  • During the COVID-19 pandemic, many small restaurants closed permanently, decreasing the overall supply of dining services in the market and shifting the supply curve leftward.

The entry or exit of firms can be caused by regulations, profit opportunities, cost changes, or market saturation. This determinant reflects the dynamic and competitive nature of most markets.

Real-world examples of supply curve shifts

Understanding how these determinants function in practice helps students connect theory to current events and business decisions.

Example 1: Food delivery services and technology

The rise of platforms like Uber Eats, DoorDash, and Grubhub shows how technology increases supply. Route optimization algorithms allow drivers to make more deliveries per hour. Restaurants using automated order systems reduce wait times. These innovations shift the supply curve for food delivery services to the right by increasing productivity and reducing delivery costs.

Example 2: Construction industry and input prices

In recent years, global disruptions caused shortages of lumber, steel, and concrete. These rising input prices made homebuilding more expensive. Many construction firms reduced production or postponed projects. As a result, the supply curve for new housing shifted left, contributing to housing shortages and higher prices in many cities.

Example 3: Gasoline and diesel as complements in production

Crude oil is refined into multiple products, including gasoline, diesel, and jet fuel. If demand for gasoline rises sharply, refiners process more crude oil, increasing the supply of diesel and jet fuel as byproducts. This demonstrates how a change in demand for one product can indirectly increase the supply of its production complements.

Example 4: Expectations in agricultural markets

Wheat farmers who anticipate poor weather conditions in future seasons may increase supply now, trying to sell as much as possible before prices spike. On the other hand, if global trade agreements are expected to improve grain export prices, farmers might store their crop and sell later, reducing current supply.

Example 5: Entry of firms into the smartphone market

The popularity and profitability of smartphones attracted many new producers, especially from emerging markets. Brands like Xiaomi, Realme, and OnePlus entered the market, increasing the number of sellers and shifting the supply curve to the right. This increase in supply made smartphones more accessible and affordable in many regions.

FAQ

Yes, government regulations are considered an indirect but important determinant of supply because they can alter production costs and influence firms' ability or willingness to produce goods. Regulations such as safety standards, environmental rules, and labor laws can increase compliance costs for producers. For example, if a government imposes stricter environmental regulations on manufacturing firms, those firms may need to invest in cleaner technology or pay fines if they fail to comply. These added costs raise the overall cost of production, leading to a decrease in supply and a leftward shift of the supply curve. On the other hand, deregulation or relaxed enforcement can reduce production costs and encourage firms to increase output, causing a rightward shift in the supply curve. The key is that regulation affects supply indirectly through changes in cost structure, rather than changing the market price of the product itself, distinguishing it as a non-price determinant.

Yes, natural disasters and weather conditions are real-world, short-run determinants of supply that can cause abrupt and significant shifts in the supply curve. These events typically affect the availability of resources or the capacity to produce goods. For example, a hurricane might damage factories, destroy crops, or disrupt transportation networks. This leads to a sudden decrease in the quantity producers can supply at any given price, shifting the supply curve to the left. In agriculture, droughts or floods can wipe out harvests, reducing supply dramatically. These supply shocks are beyond the control of producers and often result in temporary supply constraints, leading to higher market prices. Conversely, favorable weather conditions can lead to bumper crops or improved productivity, causing a rightward shift in supply. While these events are unpredictable and not part of the core list of supply determinants in textbooks, they are highly relevant in real-world market behavior and AP-level analysis.

The speed at which supply responds to changes in determinants varies by industry due to differences in production flexibility, input availability, and investment requirements. Industries with inelastic supply—such as construction, energy, or large-scale manufacturing—require long planning periods, specialized labor, or costly equipment, making it harder to adjust output quickly. For example, if input prices fall or technology improves, an oil drilling company may still take months or years to ramp up production due to permitting, drilling, and refining processes. On the other hand, industries with more elastic supply, like apparel or food services, can adapt faster to changing conditions. A restaurant, for instance, may respond to falling ingredient prices by quickly increasing its output and operating hours. The time frame also matters: in the short run, capital is fixed and limits adjustment, while in the long run, firms can enter or exit the market and invest in new production methods, allowing supply to shift more significantly.

Resource mobility—the ease with which inputs like labor, capital, and land can be reallocated across industries or uses—plays a crucial role in determining how supply responds to changes in non-price determinants. When resources are highly mobile, firms can quickly adjust to changes in input prices, technology, or other supply determinants. For example, if wages in one sector fall, workers may move to other industries offering better pay, helping maintain production levels. Similarly, if a new technology is easily adaptable across sectors, it can quickly increase supply in various industries. However, when resources are immobile or highly specialized, such as in aerospace manufacturing or nuclear energy, adjustments in supply are much slower. Firms may not be able to find or retrain workers quickly or shift capital equipment to different uses, making supply less responsive. This resource rigidity limits the magnitude of supply shifts and may prolong periods of under- or over-supply in certain markets.

Subsidies and taxes directly influence producers' costs and profit incentives, making them significant determinants of supply. A subsidy is a financial payment from the government to producers, which lowers production costs and effectively increases profitability. This incentivizes producers to supply more at each price level, causing the supply curve to shift rightward. For instance, subsidies for renewable energy producers reduce the cost of generating solar or wind power, leading to increased market supply. Conversely, taxes on production—such as excise taxes or environmental fees—raise the cost of supplying a good. This decreases firms' willingness and ability to produce at each price level, resulting in a leftward shift in the supply curve. Both tools are used by governments to influence market outcomes, correct externalities, or promote specific industries. On AP exams, it's important to recognize that both subsidies and taxes do not cause movement along the supply curve—they cause shifts due to their impact on production costs.

Practice Questions

Explain how a decrease in input prices affects the supply of a good, and illustrate the effect using a correctly labeled supply curve.

When input prices decrease, the cost of producing a good falls, making production more profitable at each price level. As a result, producers are willing and able to supply more of the good. This causes a rightward shift of the supply curve, meaning that at every price, a greater quantity is supplied. On a correctly labeled graph, the original supply curve shifts to the right, showing the increase in supply. This shift is not a movement along the curve but a change in supply due to a non-price determinant—specifically, lower input costs.

A government report predicts a future increase in the price of corn. Explain how this expectation is likely to affect the current supply of corn.

If producers expect the price of corn to rise in the future, they are likely to reduce current supply in order to sell more corn later at higher prices. This means that the current supply curve shifts to the left, as farmers withhold some of their current output from the market. This is a supply shift caused by a change in expectations, a non-price determinant of supply. On a graph, this would be shown as a leftward shift of the supply curve, indicating that at each current price, a smaller quantity of corn is supplied.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email