TutorChase logo
Login
AP Microeconomics Notes

2.3.4 Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand

Price elasticity of demand (PED) is influenced by several key factors that determine how strongly consumers respond to changes in price. Understanding these determinants helps explain why some goods have elastic demand—where quantity demanded changes significantly with a price change—while others have inelastic demand—where quantity demanded is less responsive to price changes. These factors are essential for analyzing market behavior, making business pricing decisions, and evaluating the impact of government policies.

Availability of substitutes

One of the most significant determinants of price elasticity of demand is the availability of substitute goods. Substitutes are alternative products that can satisfy the same or similar needs. When consumers can easily switch from one product to another in response to a price change, the demand for that product tends to be more elastic.

Why substitutes influence elasticity

  • If a good has many close substitutes, even a small increase in price may cause consumers to shift to competing products.

  • If few or no substitutes exist, consumers have limited alternatives and may continue purchasing the good despite price changes, leading to inelastic demand.

The responsiveness of demand largely depends on how easily consumers perceive and access alternatives.

Real-world examples

  • Elastic demand: The market for bottled water is a common example. There are numerous brands—Dasani, Aquafina, Smartwater—and if one increases its price, consumers can easily switch to a cheaper option. This creates a high degree of price elasticity.

  • Inelastic demand: For a patient who requires a specific medication like insulin, there are no effective substitutes. Even with significant price increases, the consumer has no choice but to continue purchasing it, making the demand highly inelastic.

Key ideas to remember

  • The greater the number of substitutes, the more choices consumers have, resulting in higher elasticity.

  • The fewer the substitutes, the harder it is to switch, resulting in lower elasticity.

  • Substitutability is subjective and can vary across consumers. For instance, a coffee drinker might view tea as a substitute, while another may not.

Necessity versus luxury

Another major factor influencing price elasticity of demand is whether a good is considered a necessity or a luxury. This distinction affects how willing or able consumers are to adjust their purchasing behavior when prices change.

Necessities

  • Necessities are goods that consumers need for daily living or survival, such as basic food items, water, electricity, and medical care.

  • Because these goods are essential, consumers are less responsive to price changes.

  • Even if prices rise sharply, consumers will continue to buy them, making demand relatively inelastic.

Luxuries

  • Luxury goods are non-essential items that provide added comfort, enjoyment, or prestige.

  • Examples include high-end fashion, luxury cars, concert tickets, and vacations.

  • Since these goods are not required for survival, consumers tend to reduce consumption when prices increase, making demand more elastic.

Real-world examples

  • Inelastic demand (necessity): Basic groceries like rice or bread are typically considered necessities. If the price of bread increases, most households will still purchase it, though they might cut back slightly on quantity or switch brands.

  • Elastic demand (luxury): If the price of designer handbags rises significantly, many consumers will choose not to buy them, as they are not essential purchases. This makes demand more responsive to price changes.

Additional considerations

  • The classification of a good as a necessity or luxury may vary between individuals or cultures. For one person, a smartphone might be essential; for another, a basic phone might suffice.

  • As incomes rise, some luxuries may gradually be perceived as necessities, changing the elasticity of demand over time.

Proportion of income spent on the good

The relative cost of a good compared to a consumer’s income also plays a crucial role in determining its price elasticity. Goods that consume a larger share of a person’s income are typically more elastic, while inexpensive goods tend to be inelastic.

High-cost items

  • When a product takes up a significant portion of income, price changes are more noticeable and impactful.

  • Consumers may reconsider purchases or seek cheaper alternatives, resulting in more elastic demand.

  • These goods are often considered big-ticket items—such as cars, appliances, or furniture.

Low-cost items

  • For goods that cost very little relative to income, price changes are less likely to influence purchasing behavior.

  • Even if the price of the product doubles, the absolute amount remains small, leading to more inelastic demand.

Real-world examples

  • Elastic demand: A 10% increase in the price of a laptop (say, from 1,000to1,000 to 1,100) can cause many consumers to delay purchase, shop around, or opt for a cheaper model.

  • Inelastic demand: If the price of a packet of salt rises from 1to1 to 1.20, most consumers will continue buying it, since the increase represents a tiny fraction of their income.

Income levels and elasticity

  • The proportion of income matters relative to each individual consumer. For example, a $50 restaurant meal might be elastic for a college student but inelastic for a wealthy executive.

  • As income increases, the elasticity of demand for many goods decreases, since the same price change becomes less significant relative to total income.

Time period

The amount of time consumers have to respond to a change in price affects how elastic demand will be. In general, demand is more inelastic in the short run and becomes more elastic in the long run, as consumers have time to adjust their behavior.

Short-run demand

  • In the short term, consumers have limited ability to adjust their consumption habits.

  • There may be a lack of immediate substitutes or time to research alternatives.

  • This results in lower elasticity.

Long-run demand

  • Over a longer period, consumers are able to find substitutes, adopt new habits, or make changes that reduce their dependence on the product.

  • Demand becomes more elastic as these adjustments occur.

Real-world examples

  • Short-run inelastic demand: Suppose gasoline prices rise sharply overnight. Most people still need to drive to work or school, and cannot quickly change jobs, move closer, or buy a new car. As a result, they continue buying gas despite the price hike.

  • Long-run elastic demand: Over time, if high gas prices persist, consumers may begin using public transportation, carpooling, buying more fuel-efficient vehicles, or even relocating. These long-term adaptations make demand more responsive to price, increasing elasticity.

Time and investment in alternatives

  • The more flexibility and information consumers gain over time, the more elastic demand becomes.

  • Technological change and product innovation can also increase elasticity. For example, as electric vehicles become more accessible and reliable, consumers will have more alternatives to gasoline-powered cars.

Bringing the determinants together: applied examples

Understanding the four key determinants—availability of substitutes, necessity vs. luxury, proportion of income, and time period—helps explain real consumer behavior in a wide range of markets.

Smartphones

  • Substitutes: Many similar models and brands (Apple, Samsung, Google).

  • Necessity or luxury: Perceived as a necessity by most, but luxury models exist.

  • Income share: Significant for many buyers, especially students.

  • Time period: In the short term, consumers may not delay purchase. Over time, more options and deals increase elasticity.

Overall, the demand for smartphones is moderately elastic, depending on the brand and consumer.

Cigarettes

  • Substitutes: Few substitutes for addicted smokers.

  • Necessity vs. luxury: A psychological necessity, not a physical one.

  • Income share: Can be a significant expense, especially for low-income consumers.

  • Time period: In the short run, demand is highly inelastic. Over time, with help and resources, demand becomes more elastic.

Despite high prices and taxes, demand remains relatively inelastic, especially in the short run.

College textbooks

  • Substitutes: Limited substitutes unless alternatives like digital or used books are available.

  • Necessity: Required for coursework, making them a necessity for students.

  • Income proportion: Often a high cost relative to student income.

  • Time period: Over time, students may find cheaper alternatives—used books, rentals, or online resources.

Textbook demand is generally inelastic in the short run, but more elastic in the long run as alternatives become available.

FAQ

Yes, a good can have different price elasticities of demand depending on the market or the consumer group in question. Elasticity is not a fixed property of a good; it depends on the context in which the good is being consumed. For instance, the demand for a prescription drug may be inelastic in the U.S. where insurance coverage is common, but more elastic in a market where consumers pay out-of-pocket. Similarly, a good may be a necessity for one consumer and a luxury for another. For example, a smartphone may be considered essential by a young professional for work purposes, making their demand inelastic, whereas it may be seen as a luxury by an elderly retiree who uses it only occasionally. Regional differences also affect elasticity—availability of substitutes, cultural preferences, and income levels all vary across regions, changing how consumers react to price changes. Therefore, elasticity can vary widely based on individual circumstances and market conditions.

Brand loyalty can significantly decrease the price elasticity of demand for a product. When consumers are loyal to a particular brand, they are less likely to switch to a competing product, even if the price of their preferred brand increases. This reduces the sensitivity of quantity demanded to price changes, making demand more inelastic. Loyal customers often perceive the brand as offering superior quality, trust, or emotional value that substitutes cannot provide. For example, consumers who strongly prefer Apple products may continue purchasing iPhones even after price increases, ignoring cheaper alternatives from Samsung or Google. This loyalty creates a barrier to substitution, weakening one of the key determinants of elasticity. As a result, firms with strong brand identity can raise prices without a large drop in sales, increasing their pricing power. Therefore, in markets with high brand loyalty, even products that normally would be considered elastic can experience inelastic demand.

Consumer habits can make demand more inelastic over time. When consumers repeatedly purchase a good out of habit, they are less likely to react to price changes, even when alternatives exist. Habitual consumption often reduces conscious evaluation of price, making demand less responsive. This behavior is especially common in products like coffee, cigarettes, or soft drinks, where consumption becomes part of a daily routine. For example, someone who drinks the same brand of coffee every morning may continue buying it even if the price increases significantly. The habitual nature of the purchase means the consumer might not compare prices or consider substitutes, reducing the effect of price as a decision-making factor. In this case, even though substitutes may be available and the good may not be a strict necessity, demand becomes inelastic due to behavioral patterns. Marketers often reinforce these habits through loyalty programs or branding to maintain inelastic demand.

Elasticity tends to increase over time because consumers and producers have more flexibility to adjust to price changes in the long run. Initially, when a price increases, consumers may not have the time, resources, or knowledge to find alternatives, making demand relatively inelastic. However, given enough time, consumers can seek substitutes, change their consumption patterns, or even shift their preferences. For example, if heating oil prices rise, households may not immediately reduce usage. But over several months or years, they may insulate their homes better or switch to electric heating, making demand more elastic. Producers may also introduce new competing products in response to higher prices, further increasing the availability of substitutes. In addition, changes in technology and information access allow consumers to make more informed decisions over time. Therefore, even if the good itself stays the same, the conditions around consumption evolve, leading to a more elastic response in the long run.

The broader or narrower the definition of a market, the more it influences the elasticity of demand. In general, narrowly defined markets tend to have more elastic demand, while broadly defined markets tend to have inelastic demand. This is because narrower markets include more close substitutes within the broader category. For example, the demand for “Coca-Cola” is likely more elastic than the demand for “soft drinks” in general. If the price of Coca-Cola increases, consumers can easily switch to Pepsi or another brand, showing a high responsiveness to price change. However, if the price of all soft drinks increases, there are fewer non-soft drink alternatives, making the overall demand for the category less responsive and more inelastic. The key is the availability of alternatives within the defined market. The more narrowly you define a good, the more options consumers perceive they have, and thus, the higher the elasticity of demand for that specific good.

Practice Questions

Explain how the availability of substitutes affects the price elasticity of demand for a product. Use a real-world example in your answer.

The availability of substitutes is a key determinant of price elasticity of demand. When many close substitutes exist, demand tends to be elastic because consumers can easily switch if the price rises. For example, if the price of Brand A cereal increases, many consumers will switch to Brand B or C, leading to a significant drop in quantity demanded. In contrast, if few substitutes exist, demand is inelastic. This means the more alternatives available, the more responsive consumers are to price changes, resulting in a higher elasticity of demand for the good.

A government plans to impose a tax on a good with inelastic demand. Using your understanding of elasticity determinants, explain the likely effect on total revenue and consumer burden.

When demand is inelastic, consumers are relatively unresponsive to price changes. If a government imposes a tax on such a good, total revenue is likely to increase because consumers will continue purchasing nearly the same quantity despite the higher price. Additionally, because demand is inelastic, consumers bear most of the tax burden. For instance, if the taxed good is gasoline—a necessity with few substitutes—consumers have little choice but to keep buying it, absorbing most of the price increase caused by the tax. Thus, tax revenue rises, and consumers experience the majority of the financial burden.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email