TutorChase logo
Login
AP Microeconomics Notes

2.8.2 Taxes and Subsidies

Taxes and subsidies are key tools that governments use to influence market behavior, affecting prices, production, consumption, and the overall functioning of markets.

What are taxes?

Definition and purpose

Taxes are mandatory payments imposed by the government on individuals or businesses. In microeconomics, we focus on indirect taxes, which are applied to goods and services, rather than on income or profits. These taxes are usually paid by producers or consumers when they buy or sell a product.

The government implements taxes for several purposes:

  • To raise government revenue for funding public goods and services such as roads, schools, and healthcare.

  • To discourage the consumption or production of goods considered harmful (e.g., tobacco, alcohol, sugary drinks).

  • To correct negative externalities, which are unintended harmful effects on third parties, such as pollution from factories or vehicle emissions.

Types of taxes

There are two main types of taxes applied to goods and services:

  • Specific taxes (also called per-unit taxes): A fixed amount of tax is levied per unit of a good sold. For example, a 1taxperpackofcigarettes.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>Advaloremtaxes</strong>:A<strong>percentageofthevalue</strong>ofthegoodistaxed.Forexample,a101 tax per pack of cigarettes.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Ad valorem taxes</strong>: A <strong>percentage of the value</strong> of the good is taxed. For example, a 10% sales tax on the purchase price of a product.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The effect of each type of tax on price, quantity, and market behavior differs slightly, but both shift the supply curve upward, increasing prices for consumers and reducing the quantity sold.</span></p><h2 id="what-are-subsidies"><span style="color: #001A96"><strong>What are subsidies?</strong></span></h2><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Definition and purpose</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Subsidies</strong> are <strong>financial payments made by the government</strong> to <strong>producers or consumers</strong>, aimed at <strong>encouraging production or consumption</strong> of certain goods or services. They effectively lower the cost of production or purchase, making goods more accessible or affordable.</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Governments offer subsidies for various reasons:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>To support essential industries</strong>, such as agriculture, energy, or education.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>To encourage consumption</strong> of goods with <strong>positive externalities</strong>, such as public transportation or vaccinations.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>To promote economic growth</strong>, employment, or investment in emerging sectors like renewable energy or technology.</span></p></li></ul><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Types of subsidies</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Subsidies can take multiple forms:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Direct payments</strong> to producers or firms to lower production costs.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Consumer subsidies</strong>, such as vouchers or rebates, to reduce the purchase price of a good or service.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Tax reductions or credits</strong>, which decrease the overall tax burden on producers or consumers.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Input subsidies</strong>, where the government provides resources such as seeds, fertilizers, or electricity at below-market prices.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">These forms of subsidies reduce the effective cost of producing or purchasing a good, leading to increased supply or demand, and a new market equilibrium.</span></p><h2 id="how-taxes-affect-the-supply-curve"><span style="color: #001A96"><strong>How taxes affect the supply curve</strong></span></h2><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">When a tax is imposed on a good, it increases the cost of production for firms. Because producers now receive less revenue per unit sold (due to part of the price going to the government), they are less willing to supply the same quantity at each price level.</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">This results in a <strong>leftward or upward shift of the supply curve</strong>. The size of the shift is equal to the <strong>amount of the tax per unit</strong>.</span></p><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Visual description of a tax graph</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Consider a supply and demand diagram:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The initial equilibrium is at point E1, where the original supply curve (S1) intersects the demand curve (D).</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">A <strong>specific tax</strong> causes the supply curve to shift upward to S2.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At the new equilibrium point E2:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>price paid by consumers</strong> rises from P1 to Pc.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>price received by producers</strong> falls from P1 to Pp.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>quantity sold</strong> falls from Q1 to Q2.</span></p></li></ul></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>difference between Pc and Pp</strong> is the <strong>tax per unit</strong>.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>government's tax revenue</strong> is calculated as:<br> <strong>Tax revenue = (Pc - Pp) × Q2</strong></span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">This area can be visualized as a rectangle between the two price levels, extending horizontally to the new quantity sold.</span></p><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Impact on the market</strong></span></h3><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Higher prices for consumers</strong> may reduce demand, especially for elastic goods.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Lower revenue for producers</strong> reduces supply and may lead to job losses or business closures in some industries.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Reduced quantity sold</strong> indicates lower market efficiency.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government gains revenue</strong>, which can be used for public services or to offset negative externalities.</span></p></li></ul><h2 id="how-subsidies-affect-the-supply-curve"><span style="color: #001A96"><strong>How subsidies affect the supply curve</strong></span></h2><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">When a subsidy is granted, producers receive additional income for every unit sold. This reduces their cost of production and allows them to sell the product at a lower market price while maintaining profitability.</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The supply curve shifts <strong>downward or to the right</strong>, reflecting an increase in supply at every price level. The vertical distance between the old and new supply curve equals the subsidy amount per unit.</span></p><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Visual description of a subsidy graph</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">In a typical supply and demand graph:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The original supply curve (S1) intersects the demand curve (D) at equilibrium point E1.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">A <strong>subsidy</strong> shifts the supply curve downward to S2.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At the new equilibrium point E2:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>price paid by consumers</strong> falls from P1 to Pc.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>price received by producers</strong> rises from P1 to Pp (Pc plus the subsidy).</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>quantity sold</strong> increases from Q1 to Q2.</span></p></li></ul></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The <strong>government’s cost of the subsidy</strong> is calculated as:<br><br> <strong>Subsidy cost = (Pp - Pc) × Q2</strong></span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">This is the area between the producer's revenue and the consumer’s payment, multiplied by the quantity sold.</span></p><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Impact on the market</strong></span></h3><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Lower prices for consumers</strong> make the product more accessible and stimulate demand.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Higher effective revenue for producers</strong> encourages greater production and investment.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Increased quantity sold</strong> reflects higher market activity and potential economic growth.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government bears the financial cost</strong>, which may be significant, especially if demand is highly elastic.</span></p></li></ul><h2 id="effects-of-taxes-on-government-revenue"><span style="color: #001A96"><strong>Effects of taxes on government revenue</strong></span></h2><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Taxes are a primary tool for governments to collect money. The <strong>total tax revenue</strong> generated depends on several factors:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Size of the tax</strong>: A larger per-unit tax increases potential revenue per unit.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Quantity sold after the tax</strong>: If the tax significantly reduces demand, the total number of units sold may fall, limiting total revenue.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Price elasticity of demand and supply</strong>:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">If <strong>demand is inelastic</strong>, consumers are less sensitive to price changes, so quantity sold remains relatively high, and revenue is maximized.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">If <strong>demand is elastic</strong>, quantity sold falls sharply in response to the price increase, and tax revenue may be lower than expected.</span></p></li></ul></li></ul><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Tax revenue formula</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government tax revenue = tax per unit × quantity sold after tax</strong></span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">For example:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">A 2 tax per unit is imposed on soft drinks.

  • If 1 million units are sold after the tax, then:

    Revenue = 2×1,000,000=2 × 1,000,000 = 2,000,000

If the tax is too high and significantly reduces the quantity sold, total revenue could decrease, demonstrating the Laffer curve concept, which shows the relationship between tax rates and revenue.

Real-world example

Suppose a government imposes a 0.50excisetaxoneachgallonofgasoline.Beforethetax,2billiongallonsweresold.Afterthetax,salesfallto1.8billiongallons.</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>Governmentrevenue=0.50 excise tax on each gallon of gasoline. Before the tax, 2 billion gallons were sold. After the tax, sales fall to 1.8 billion gallons.</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government revenue = 0.50 × 1.8 billion = 900 million</strong></span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The tax reduces consumption (a possible policy goal) but also alters market equilibrium.</span></p><h2 id="effects-of-subsidies-on-government-costs"><span style="color: #001A96"><strong>Effects of subsidies on government costs</strong></span></h2><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">While subsidies can stimulate production and consumption, they require <strong>direct expenditure</strong> from the government budget. The <strong>total cost</strong> of providing a subsidy depends on:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>The subsidy amount per unit</strong>: Larger subsidies increase total spending.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>The quantity sold with the subsidy</strong>: If the subsidy causes a large rise in sales, total costs can grow rapidly.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Elasticity of demand and supply</strong>:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">With <strong>elastic demand</strong>, a small price decrease causes a large increase in quantity sold, leading to higher government costs.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">With <strong>inelastic demand</strong>, the quantity sold increases only slightly, so total cost is more stable.</span></p></li></ul></li></ul><h3><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Subsidy cost formula</strong></span></h3><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government cost = subsidy per unit × quantity sold after subsidy</strong></span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">For example:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">A 1.50 subsidy is given per unit of a renewable energy product.

  • If 700,000 units are sold after the subsidy:
    Government cost = 1.50×700,000=1.50 × 700,000 = 1,050,000

  • This cost must be weighed against the policy's benefits, such as reduced emissions or job creation.

    Real-world example

    The government offers a 1,000subsidyonelectricvehicles(EVs).</span></p><ul><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Beforethesubsidy,100,000EVsweresoldannually.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Afterthesubsidy,salesriseto160,000vehicles.</span></p></li></ul><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>Governmentcost=1,000 subsidy on electric vehicles (EVs).</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Before the subsidy, 100,000 EVs were sold annually.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">After the subsidy, sales rise to 160,000 vehicles.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Government cost = 1,000 × 160,000 = $160 million

    This promotes cleaner transportation but represents a significant budgetary commitment.

    FAQ

    The impact of a tax on the quantity sold depends largely on the price elasticities of demand and supply, not just the tax amount. If a good has elastic demand, consumers are highly responsive to price changes, so even a small increase in price due to a tax leads to a large decrease in quantity demanded. For example, luxury goods or non-essential items often have elastic demand, so taxing them significantly reduces sales. In contrast, if demand is inelastic, such as for essential medications or gasoline, consumers continue to purchase despite higher prices, leading to a smaller decrease in quantity sold. The supply elasticity also matters—if supply is elastic, producers can easily reduce output when taxed, decreasing the quantity sold further. So, even if the per-unit tax is identical, the relative responsiveness of consumers and producers determines how drastically the market contracts in response to the tax.

    Yes, subsidies can sometimes lead to overproduction and inefficient resource allocation, especially when they distort market signals. When producers receive financial support regardless of actual consumer demand, they may produce more than what the market would efficiently support. This can result in surpluses, which either go unsold or require further government intervention to manage—such as storage, destruction, or purchasing the excess. A historical example is agricultural subsidies, where farmers are encouraged to grow more crops, even if there is no increase in market demand. Over time, this leads to inefficiency, as resources like land, labor, and capital are diverted from potentially more productive uses. Additionally, the government ends up spending taxpayer money on goods that are not always needed, reducing overall economic welfare. Thus, while subsidies can correct market failures or support emerging industries, poorly targeted or excessive subsidies can cause allocative inefficiency.

    The decision to tax producers or consumers is often strategic and depends on both economic and political factors. Economically, the legal incidence of the tax (who officially pays it) is less important than the economic incidence (who actually bears the burden). The true burden depends on price elasticity: the side of the market that is less elastic will bear more of the tax. However, policymakers still choose a formal point of collection—either producers (e.g., excise taxes on manufacturers) or consumers (e.g., sales taxes at checkout). Politically, taxing producers may be less visible to consumers, making it more acceptable, while taxing consumers directly may generate more public backlash, especially if the tax is regressive. Administrative efficiency also plays a role—it's often easier to collect taxes from a small number of producers than from millions of consumers. Ultimately, while who remits the tax may vary, market forces determine how the tax burden is distributed.

    Some subsidies fail to significantly increase output or consumption due to inelastic supply or demand, bottlenecks, or external constraints. If demand is inelastic, lowering the price through a subsidy doesn’t encourage consumers to buy much more—this is common in products people either must or must not buy, like certain medications or addictive goods. Similarly, if supply is inelastic, producers may be unable to increase output even with more revenue. For example, in industries where production is limited by natural resources, regulations, or capacity constraints (such as housing or renewable energy), subsidies may have limited effect. In addition, administrative delays, lack of information, or mistrust about receiving subsidies can prevent firms or consumers from responding as expected. Also, if subsidies are temporary or small, producers may not find it worth adjusting their output plans. Thus, effectiveness depends on the responsiveness of market participants and the broader market environment.

    Taxing goods with inelastic demand often leads to high government revenue, but it can also create significant equity concerns and unintended market effects. Since consumers are less responsive to price increases, they continue buying the product despite the higher cost, resulting in a heavier burden on consumers. This is especially problematic if the taxed good is a necessity—such as utilities, fuel, or food—because lower-income individuals spend a larger share of their income on these items. As a result, the tax can be regressive, disproportionately affecting those who can least afford it. Additionally, heavy taxation may lead to black market activity or illegal production, especially if the taxed item has addictive or habitual consumption patterns, like tobacco or alcohol. These consequences can undermine both the effectiveness and fairness of the tax policy, requiring complementary measures such as rebates, exemptions, or targeted subsidies to protect vulnerable groups.

    Practice Questions

    A government imposes a $2 per-unit tax on a good with relatively inelastic demand. Using supply and demand analysis, explain the likely effects of this tax on the equilibrium price and quantity, the burden on consumers and producers, and government revenue.

    When a 2perunittaxisimposedonagoodwithinelasticdemand,thesupplycurveshiftsupwardby2 per-unit tax is imposed on a good with inelastic demand, the supply curve shifts upward by 2. The equilibrium price rises, and the quantity decreases slightly due to inelastic demand. Because consumers are less responsive to price changes, they bear most of the tax burden. Producers receive a lower effective price, but the decrease in quantity sold is small. The government earns substantial revenue equal to $2 multiplied by the post-tax quantity sold. This policy generates revenue efficiently but places most of the financial burden on consumers, especially if the good is a necessity like gasoline or medicine.

    The government introduces a per-unit subsidy for producers of solar panels. Explain how this affects the market supply, equilibrium price and quantity, producer revenue, and government expenditure.

    A per-unit subsidy lowers production costs, shifting the supply curve downward by the subsidy amount. This results in a lower equilibrium price for consumers and a higher equilibrium quantity. Producers receive both the market price and the subsidy, increasing their total revenue. As more solar panels are sold, government expenditure rises and is calculated by multiplying the subsidy amount by the quantity sold. The market experiences increased output and lower prices, aligning with goals such as promoting renewable energy. However, the government must consider the long-term cost of funding the subsidy as more firms enter the market due to increased profitability.

    Hire a tutor

    Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

    1/2
    Your details
    Alternatively contact us via
    WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email