TutorChase logo
Login
Edexcel A-Level Economics Study Notes

1.2.10 Alternative Views of Consumer Behaviour

Rational consumer behaviour assumes people always make logical, benefit-maximising choices. However, real-world decisions often defy this, revealing behavioural complexities beyond standard economic models.

The assumption of rational consumer behaviour

In classical economic theory, consumers are treated as rational economic agents. This means they are assumed to:

  • Possess complete and accurate information.

  • Analyse this information efficiently.

  • Always act in a way that maximises their utility, or satisfaction from consumption.

This model is based on the idea that individuals can weigh up the costs and benefits of every possible choice and then select the one that gives them the greatest net gain. In this framework, consumers are unemotional, analytical, and forward-thinking.

For example, a rational consumer deciding between two brands of bread will consider factors such as price, quality, quantity, and personal preference. They will choose the brand that provides the most utility for the lowest price.

However, in the real world, this rational model is often violated. Many decisions are made without full information, influenced by social context, emotions, or mental shortcuts, leading to outcomes that may not maximise individual welfare. This has led to the rise of behavioural economics, a field that integrates insights from psychology into economic theory.

Non-rational influences on consumer behaviour

Behavioural economists argue that consumer decisions are often shaped by non-rational factors, which result in systematic deviations from rationality. These include:

Influence of others

Human beings are social creatures. Our preferences and choices are frequently influenced by the actions and opinions of others, whether consciously or unconsciously.

Peer pressure

Peer pressure refers to the influence that social groups have on individual decision-making. Consumers often make purchases or adopt behaviours simply to conform or gain acceptance.

  • This is especially common among teenagers and young adults, who may purchase certain fashion brands, gadgets, or food items just because their friends do.

  • The desire to "fit in" or not be excluded can override rational decision-making.

Example: A student may buy the latest smartphone model, not because of its features, but to maintain social status within their peer group.

Herd behaviour

Herding describes situations where individuals imitate the actions of a larger group, assuming that the group collectively knows better or cannot all be wrong.

  • Herd behaviour can lead to irrational outcomes like market bubbles or panic buying.

  • It is particularly prevalent in fast-moving or uncertain markets.

Example: Many people invested in cryptocurrencies like Bitcoin in the late 2010s, not because they understood the asset, but because others were doing so. As a result, prices were driven up without solid fundamentals, illustrating herd behaviour at a large scale.

Habitual behaviour

In many cases, consumers do not actively think through every choice. Instead, they rely on habits—automatic behaviours formed through repetition.

  • Habit reduces mental effort and saves time but can lead to inefficient choices.

  • Habitual decisions are especially common for low-cost, routine purchases such as food, toiletries, and transport.

Example: A person might buy the same brand of toothpaste every month, not because it is the best value or most effective, but simply because it is what they are used to.

Habitual behaviour is often reinforced by businesses using loyalty schemes, product placement, or advertising repetition to ensure brand recall and maintain consumer routines.

Computational weaknesses

Humans have limited mental capacity for making complex calculations, especially under time pressure or uncertainty. This is known as bounded rationality.

Difficulty comparing prices

Many consumers find it hard to accurately compare prices, particularly when faced with multi-buy offers, different unit sizes, or hidden costs.

  • Businesses may exploit this using tactics like decoy pricing (offering an overpriced third option to make another appear more attractive) or complex bundle pricing.

Example: A shopper sees a deal of “Buy one, get one 50% off” and chooses it over a simple 30% off, even if the latter is cheaper per unit.

Estimating future value

People often struggle to make decisions involving future outcomes, such as saving, investing, or borrowing.

  • This is due to present bias, where individuals heavily discount future benefits in favour of immediate rewards.

  • As a result, they may make short-sighted choices that harm their long-term welfare.

Example: A person may take out a high-interest payday loan to fund an unnecessary purchase, undervaluing the future repayment burden.

Real-life examples of non-rational behaviour

Understanding non-rational behaviour is enhanced through real-world observations:

  • Peer influence in fashion: Teenagers buy designer trainers or branded jackets to match their friends, regardless of comfort or cost.

  • Herding in asset markets: Investors rush to buy stocks or property when the media suggests prices are rising, leading to unsustainable bubbles.

  • Habitual grocery shopping: Shoppers purchase the same cereal every week without checking for better offers or considering healthier options.

  • Mobile phone plans: Consumers often choose complex, expensive contracts bundled with unnecessary services because they are promoted with persuasive marketing, even when SIM-only deals offer better value.

These examples demonstrate how deviations from rationality occur across different income groups and product categories.

Implications for behavioural economics

The study of these non-rational behaviours has led to the development of behavioural economics, which seeks to create more accurate models of consumer choice.

Key concepts

  • Bounded rationality: Consumers aim to be rational but are limited by time, information, and mental capacity.

  • Heuristics: Mental shortcuts that simplify decision-making but can lead to errors. For example, the “availability heuristic” leads people to overestimate risks that are more memorable (e.g., plane crashes).

  • Loss aversion: The idea that losses feel more painful than gains feel rewarding. For example, losing £100 hurts more than the satisfaction of gaining £100.

  • Framing effects: How a choice is presented influences decisions, even if the underlying information is the same.

These insights help explain why consumers sometimes avoid switching energy suppliers, forget to cancel subscriptions, or fail to choose optimal savings accounts.

Policy implications: nudging and defaults

Governments and institutions use behavioural insights to improve policy design, especially in areas where traditional approaches have limited impact.

Nudges

A nudge is a policy tool that influences decisions without restricting options or significantly changing incentives.

  • Nudges aim to make the desired behaviour easier or more likely while preserving freedom of choice.

Examples of nudging:

  • Putting fruit at eye level in school canteens to encourage healthy eating.

  • Sending reminders or “social norm” messages, such as “9 out of 10 people in your area have already paid their taxes.”

  • Highlighting default pension contribution rates on enrolment forms.

These interventions often cost little but significantly influence behaviour by guiding rather than forcing choices.

Default options

People have a strong tendency toward inertia. They tend to accept default options, even when better alternatives exist.

  • Policymakers use this insight by designing default choices that are beneficial to individuals and society.

Examples:

  • Pension schemes: Auto-enrolment policies where workers are enrolled by default, with the option to opt out, have increased participation rates dramatically.

  • Organ donation: Countries with opt-out organ donation systems have higher consent rates compared to opt-in systems.

Defaults are powerful because they reduce the need for action and remove decision fatigue.

Framing and presentation

The way information is presented can dramatically affect choices.

Example:

  • A food item labelled “90% fat-free” is more appealing than one labelled “10% fat”, even though both are identical.

  • Presenting health risk statistics as “1 in 10 chance” vs “90% chance of survival” leads to different perceptions, even with the same data.

Framing tools can be used in public health campaigns, financial planning advice, and even climate change messaging to encourage positive behavioural change.

Behavioural Insights Teams

The UK’s Behavioural Insights Team (BIT), often called the “Nudge Unit,” has pioneered government use of behavioural science.

  • It has applied nudging in areas such as tax collection, health, education, and energy use.

  • In one study, sending letters to late taxpayers that said “most people in your area have already paid” increased compliance rates.

BIT’s success has inspired similar teams around the world, showing the power of behavioural tools in public policy.

Behavioural economics in the private sector

Firms use behavioural insights not just to understand consumers, but also to guide purchasing decisions in ways that increase sales and loyalty.

Choice architecture

The way options are structured and presented (online or in-store) influences decisions.

  • Restaurants might list a high-priced item first to make others seem more affordable.

  • Websites often highlight a “most popular” plan to guide users toward it.

Anchoring

Consumers are influenced by the first piece of information they receive.

Example: Showing an expensive product first (like a £3000 sofa) makes a £1500 sofa seem more reasonable, even if it exceeds the buyer’s original budget.

Personalised marketing

Firms use data to trigger emotional or habitual responses, such as offering reminders to reorder products or using algorithms to suggest new items based on past behaviour.

Example: Streaming services like Netflix use autoplay features, curated content suggestions, and push notifications to keep users engaged, making decisions easy and reducing the chance of unsubscribing.

These techniques are designed to minimise mental effort and exploit non-rational tendencies, increasing consumer engagement and spending.

FAQ

Emotions play a significant role in shaping consumer decisions, often leading individuals to act irrationally. While traditional economics assumes people act logically to maximise utility, emotions such as fear, excitement, guilt, or frustration can override careful analysis. For example, consumers may engage in impulse buying when feeling happy or excited, purchasing items they do not need simply for the emotional thrill. Alternatively, fear of missing out (FOMO) can push consumers to buy products during sales events like Black Friday, regardless of actual need or value. Emotional responses are also triggered by advertising techniques using imagery, music, or slogans designed to evoke specific feelings. These emotional cues bypass rational thought processes and encourage quicker, less deliberative actions. Additionally, emotional states can impair judgment—someone feeling anxious may avoid making decisions altogether or overvalue short-term reassurance, leading to poor long-term outcomes. Emotional decision-making challenges the assumption that consumers consistently evaluate options based on objective utility.

Choice overload occurs when consumers are faced with too many options, leading to confusion, indecision, or suboptimal choices. Although more choice should theoretically improve utility by offering better matches to preferences, psychological studies show that excessive choice often leads to decision fatigue, anxiety, or regret. For example, when faced with 30 varieties of jam in a supermarket, a consumer may feel overwhelmed, delay the decision, or revert to a habitual or random choice, even if it’s not optimal. This behaviour contradicts rational economic models, which assume consumers can process large amounts of information and compare alternatives efficiently. In practice, consumers often use shortcuts or heuristics, such as choosing the most familiar brand or the middle-priced option, rather than conducting a full cost-benefit analysis. As a result, choice overload leads to irrational behaviour—not due to lack of preferences, but due to cognitive limitations and stress linked to excessive complexity in decision-making environments.

Mental accounting refers to the way consumers categorise and treat money differently depending on its source or intended use, often leading to inconsistent decision-making. This concept, developed by behavioural economist Richard Thaler, shows that people do not view all money as equally fungible, as classical economics assumes. For example, a consumer might splurge on an expensive dinner using a £100 gift voucher but hesitate to spend the same amount from their monthly grocery budget. Similarly, individuals may treat tax refunds as “bonus money” to be spent on luxuries, rather than saving or paying off debt. These behaviours demonstrate irrationality because the value of money should remain constant, regardless of how it is labelled. Budgeting strategies may also be overly rigid—someone may refuse to exceed their “entertainment” budget even if a one-time experience would deliver greater utility. Mental accounting helps consumers manage spending but often leads to economically inconsistent choices, especially when emotional framing overrides rational valuation.

Anchoring bias is a cognitive shortcut where individuals rely heavily on the first piece of information they receive—known as the "anchor"—when making decisions. In consumer behaviour, this often manifests in how people perceive price and value. For instance, if a shirt is displayed with a “was £80, now £40” tag, the £80 becomes the anchor, making £40 seem like a bargain, even if the shirt’s true value is much lower. This pricing tactic is common in retail and online sales to manipulate perceived savings. Anchoring can also affect negotiations, where the initial price suggested often skews expectations and final agreements. Even irrelevant or arbitrary anchors can influence decisions—studies show that people will estimate higher values when presented with unrelated high numbers beforehand. This bias challenges rational behaviour by demonstrating that consumers do not independently assess value; instead, their reference points are easily manipulated by how information is presented, leading to irrational spending choices.

Yes, while default options are often effective in steering consumers towards beneficial outcomes, they can also produce negative effects if poorly designed or misaligned with individual preferences. Defaults take advantage of consumer inertia—most people stick with the pre-set choice due to effort avoidance or trust in authority. In cases where defaults reflect general best practices (e.g., pension auto-enrolment), the impact is largely positive. However, if defaults are chosen for commercial or bureaucratic convenience, they may result in consumers accepting inferior products, unfavourable contracts, or unnecessary services. For example, default subscription renewals may lead users to continue paying for services they no longer use, purely because cancelling requires time and effort. Similarly, insurance policies with high excess charges may be set as defaults, leading to reduced coverage if the consumer does not opt out. In such instances, default settings exploit cognitive bias to the consumer's detriment, highlighting the need for ethical and transparent default design in both public and private sectors.

Practice Questions

Explain how habitual behaviour might lead consumers to make suboptimal purchasing decisions.

Habitual behaviour occurs when consumers repeat past choices without re-evaluating them. This can lead to suboptimal decisions, as they may overlook better alternatives due to routine. For example, a shopper may consistently buy the same brand of cereal, ignoring new options that are cheaper or healthier. Habits reduce cognitive effort but limit responsiveness to price or quality changes. Over time, this can mean consumers spend more or gain less satisfaction than they could. In competitive markets, habitual behaviour undermines consumer sovereignty and can result in firms maintaining market share despite offering poor value or low innovation.

Evaluate the effectiveness of nudges as a tool for influencing consumer behaviour.

Nudges are effective because they guide choices without restricting freedom or using monetary incentives. For instance, auto-enrolment in pension schemes significantly increased participation by exploiting inertia. Nudges are low-cost and simple, relying on framing, social norms, or defaults. However, their effectiveness can be limited if the behavioural insight is misapplied or if consumers are unaware of the nudge. Ethical concerns also arise, as nudges may manipulate choices without transparency. Moreover, not all behaviours respond well to nudging—complex or high-stakes decisions might require stronger policy tools. Overall, nudges can be powerful but are not a one-size-fits-all solution.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email