TutorChase logo
Login
Edexcel A-Level Economics Study Notes

2.1.4 Balance of Payments and Trade

The balance of payments records all economic transactions between a country and the rest of the world, providing key insights into economic health and external relationships.

What is the balance of payments?

The balance of payments (BoP) is a statistical statement that summarises economic transactions between residents of a country and the rest of the world during a specific time period, usually a year or a quarter. It reflects all inflows (credits) and outflows (debits) of money related to trade, investment, and transfers.

The BoP is essential for understanding a country’s external position—how it interacts with the global economy. A balanced BoP means the sum of all financial flows (including trade, investments, and currency reserves) equals zero: all inflows are matched by outflows. However, individual parts of the BoP, especially the current account, may show a surplus or deficit.

The main components of the balance of payments

The BoP is structured into three major components:

1. Current account

This is the most closely analysed part of the BoP as it directly reflects trade and income from abroad. It has four main elements:

  • Trade in goods: Also known as visible trade, this covers physical products. Examples include oil, cars, food, and manufactured goods. A positive balance (exports > imports) results in a surplus; a negative balance leads to a deficit.

  • Trade in services: Known as invisible trade, it includes activities such as tourism, insurance, education, banking, and consultancy. The UK often runs a surplus in services, especially financial and professional services.

  • Primary income: Covers income from foreign investments and employment. This includes interest, dividends, and wages received from abroad, minus similar payments made to foreign investors in the UK.

  • Secondary income (current transfers): These are unilateral transfers where no goods or services are exchanged. Examples include remittances sent by workers to their families abroad, overseas aid, and contributions to international organisations.

2. Capital account

This component records capital transfers and the acquisition or disposal of non-produced, non-financial assets such as patents, copyrights, and trademarks. It is typically small and does not play a major role in economic analysis at A-Level.

3. Financial account

This records transactions involving financial assets and liabilities between residents and non-residents. It is subdivided into:

  • Direct investment: Investment where the investor gains a lasting interest, such as acquiring more than 10% of a foreign business.

  • Portfolio investment: Includes shares, bonds, and other financial instruments. It represents short-term and less-influential holdings.

  • Other investments: Includes loans, bank deposits, and trade credit.

  • Reserve assets: Foreign currency reserves held by the Bank of England or central banks to manage exchange rates and provide liquidity.

Every transaction recorded in the current and capital accounts is matched by a corresponding entry in the financial account or reserves, ensuring the BoP always balances overall.

Balance of trade and the current account

Understanding the balance of trade

The balance of trade is the difference between a country’s exports and imports of goods and services. It is a key part of the current account and is split into:

  • Goods (visible trade): Exporting manufactured goods, raw materials, and consumer products.

  • Services (invisible trade): Providing services like education, finance, and tourism to foreign consumers.

  • A trade surplus means the value of exports exceeds imports, which positively contributes to the current account. A trade deficit means the opposite.

In the UK, the balance of trade in goods is typically negative due to high imports of consumer and industrial goods, while the balance of services is usually positive, reflecting strength in sectors like finance and business services.

Why the balance of trade matters

The balance of trade influences employment, exchange rates, and growth. It also reflects the competitiveness of domestic industries. A persistent trade deficit may signal underlying structural weaknesses, such as low productivity or overreliance on consumption.

Current account deficits and surpluses

What is a current account deficit?

A current account deficit occurs when a country’s total imports of goods, services, income, and transfers exceed its total exports. It implies that the country is spending more on foreign-produced goods and services than it earns from selling domestically produced goods and services abroad.

In basic terms:
Current account balance = Exports - Imports + Net Primary Income + Net Transfers

If the result is negative, it’s a deficit. This may be financed through borrowing, attracting foreign investment, or drawing on reserves.

What is a current account surplus?

A surplus arises when total inflows from exports, investment income, and transfers exceed outflows. This reflects high savings, strong export performance, or limited imports.

Countries like Germany and China often run surpluses due to strong industrial exports and high domestic savings rates.

Causes of imbalances

Key factors leading to deficits or surpluses include:

  • Domestic income levels: Higher income often increases imports, widening deficits.

  • Exchange rates: A strong currency makes exports expensive and imports cheap, worsening the current account.

  • Competitiveness: Poor productivity or high labour costs make exports less competitive.

  • Inflation differentials: Higher inflation at home discourages exports and encourages imports.

  • Consumption patterns: High consumer demand for foreign goods increases imports.

  • Structural factors: Lack of industrial capacity or overreliance on raw material exports can shape trade balances.

Impacts of deficits and surpluses

Effects of current account deficits

  • Exchange rate pressure: A deficit may lead to depreciation of the national currency as demand for foreign currency rises.

  • Rising debt: If deficits are financed by borrowing, national debt increases, leading to future interest burdens.

  • Investor confidence: Persistent deficits can erode investor confidence, causing capital flight and financial instability.

  • Inflationary impact: Currency depreciation can raise import prices, fuelling inflation.

  • Dependency: Deficits may increase dependence on foreign creditors and investors.

Effects of current account surpluses

  • Currency appreciation: Surpluses may lead to a stronger currency, which can reduce export competitiveness over time.

  • Inflation control: High exports may help contain inflation by boosting supply-side capacity.

  • Strained trade relations: Large surpluses can lead to friction with trade partners who experience deficits.

  • Internal imbalance: Excessive focus on exports might come at the expense of domestic consumption and investment.

Relationship with other macroeconomic objectives

The current account interacts with major macroeconomic goals:

Inflation

  • Deficit-induced inflation: A falling exchange rate due to a deficit makes imports more expensive, leading to cost-push inflation.

  • Surplus-induced deflationary pressures: Persistent surpluses may keep domestic demand low, reducing inflation.

Unemployment

  • Deficits may reduce domestic production, raising unemployment in trade-sensitive sectors.

  • Surpluses encourage production and exports, supporting employment, especially in export-oriented industries.

Economic growth

  • A moderate deficit may stimulate growth if it funds productive investment (e.g., importing capital goods).

  • Surpluses can drive export-led growth, but overreliance may create vulnerabilities if external demand falls.

Exchange rate stability

  • Deficits can cause volatile exchange rate movements, reducing investor confidence and increasing uncertainty.

  • Surpluses often stabilise exchange rates but can create pressure for appreciation, impacting future trade balances.

Global interconnectedness via trade

Trade interdependence

In the 21st century, countries are highly interdependent. The UK, for instance, depends on imported energy, raw materials, and intermediate goods. In turn, other nations rely on UK services and investment.

This interdependence has grown due to free trade agreements, digital connectivity, and capital mobility. No country is economically isolated—economic policies and events in one state can quickly influence others.

Global supply chains

Global supply chains divide the production process across multiple countries to exploit comparative advantages. For example:

  • A car might be designed in Germany, have parts produced in Japan, assembled in Mexico, and sold in the UK.

These supply chains reduce costs and improve efficiency, but they also increase systemic risk. A disruption (e.g., COVID-19, natural disasters, conflict) in one link can affect the entire chain.

External shocks

The modern economy is vulnerable to external shocks transmitted via trade and investment. Examples include:

  • Financial crises: The 2008 global financial crisis originated in the US but spread rapidly through trade and financial links.

  • Pandemics: COVID-19 shut down global trade routes, disrupted supply chains, and collapsed tourism and service exports.

  • Energy shocks: Price changes in oil and gas ripple across countries through production costs and trade balances.

The role of globalisation

Globalisation has intensified economic interconnectedness, with both benefits and drawbacks:

Benefits

  • Specialisation and efficiency: Countries can focus on producing goods and services in which they are most efficient.

  • Lower prices: Consumers access a greater variety of cheaper goods.

  • Market access: Firms can expand operations and reach customers worldwide.

Drawbacks

  • Vulnerability: Interconnectedness exposes countries to foreign demand shocks and global crises.

  • Loss of sovereignty: National economic policies may be constrained by international trade rules and capital flows.

  • Inequality: Benefits may be unequally distributed, leading to domestic backlash and protectionism.

In this context, the balance of payments provides a crucial tool for understanding a country’s external performance, its position within the global economy, and the pressures it faces in an interconnected world.

FAQ

The UK usually runs a current account deficit, mainly due to a persistent trade deficit in goods. The UK imports a large volume of goods, including consumer electronics, fuel, and raw materials, which reflects strong domestic demand and limited domestic manufacturing. Meanwhile, although the UK runs a surplus in services—particularly in finance, education, and legal services—this often isn't enough to offset the goods deficit. Additionally, high income from abroad (such as dividends and interest) has declined relative to payments made to foreign investors in the UK. While a deficit may seem negative, it is not necessarily a sign of economic weakness. If the deficit is financed by stable and productive capital inflows—like foreign direct investment—it may support growth. A deficit might also indicate a dynamic economy with confident consumers. However, long-term reliance on external finance can pose risks if investor confidence declines or if global conditions tighten.

Central banks play a critical role in managing balance of payments imbalances through their influence on exchange rates, interest rates, and foreign currency reserves. If a country faces a large current account deficit and downward pressure on its currency, the central bank might intervene by selling foreign reserves to support the domestic currency. This stabilises exchange rates and helps limit inflation caused by rising import prices. Additionally, central banks may adjust interest rates to influence capital flows; for instance, raising interest rates can attract portfolio investment, boosting demand for the domestic currency and offsetting a current account deficit. In the long run, central banks may coordinate with governments to enhance competitiveness by encouraging structural reforms. However, persistent intervention can be costly and unsustainable, especially if reserve levels are low. Therefore, while central banks can respond to short-term imbalances, long-term correction usually depends on broader economic adjustments such as improving productivity and export performance.

Demographic trends have a significant influence on a country’s current account balance through their effects on consumption, savings, and labour market dynamics. A younger population tends to consume more and save less, which may lead to increased imports and a higher likelihood of running a current account deficit. In contrast, ageing populations often save more, especially in developed countries where retirees rely on accumulated wealth, potentially leading to a surplus. For example, countries like Japan and Germany, with older populations, often exhibit high savings rates and large current account surpluses. Additionally, a growing working-age population can boost export capacity by expanding the labour force, especially if matched with sufficient education and infrastructure. However, if population growth outpaces domestic production capacity, it can increase demand for imports, worsening the current account. Migration patterns also play a role—net immigration may increase remittances sent abroad (a debit in the current account), but can also enhance productive capacity.

Government fiscal policy affects the current account primarily through its influence on aggregate demand. Expansionary fiscal policy—increasing government spending or cutting taxes—raises national income and consumption. This often leads to higher demand for imports, worsening the trade balance and increasing the current account deficit. For example, a tax cut that boosts disposable income may encourage households to purchase imported goods, adding to the import bill. On the other hand, contractionary fiscal policy can reduce import demand, helping to narrow a current account deficit. Additionally, fiscal policy impacts the exchange rate indirectly; higher government borrowing may lead to interest rate changes that affect capital inflows and the currency's value. If spending is focused on productivity-enhancing investments (such as infrastructure or education), it may improve the long-run export capacity and help correct a deficit. However, fiscal policy’s effect on the current account depends on its scale, duration, and the openness of the economy to trade and investment.

Commodity prices have a profound effect on the balance of payments in countries that rely heavily on exporting raw materials such as oil, metals, or agricultural products. When global commodity prices rise, these countries experience higher export earnings, improving the trade balance and potentially leading to a current account surplus. For instance, an oil-exporting country like Nigeria or Saudi Arabia may see large surpluses during oil booms. This inflow of foreign currency strengthens the financial account through increased reserves or investment. Conversely, when prices fall, export revenues drop sharply, often resulting in trade deficits and pressure on the currency. These countries may then struggle to finance imports and debt payments, especially if they lack diversification. Volatile commodity prices also make economic planning difficult, leading to procyclical fiscal policies. To manage this, some countries create stabilisation funds or sovereign wealth funds to save windfall revenues, helping smooth the impact on the BoP during price fluctuations.

Practice Questions

Analyse two possible impacts of a persistent current account deficit on the UK economy.

A persistent current account deficit may lead to downward pressure on the value of sterling as demand for foreign currency increases, potentially causing depreciation. This would make imports more expensive, leading to cost-push inflation. Additionally, the deficit might indicate over-reliance on foreign borrowing to finance spending, increasing national debt and future interest payments. Investor confidence could fall, reducing foreign direct investment inflows. If unchecked, such deficits might constrain long-term economic growth, reduce policy flexibility, and heighten vulnerability to external shocks. However, if the deficit funds productive investment, its long-term effects could be less negative.

Evaluate the extent to which a current account surplus is beneficial for an economy.

A current account surplus can reflect strong export performance, supporting economic growth and employment in export sectors. It may also indicate a net inflow of foreign income, improving national savings and reducing the need for borrowing. However, excessive surpluses may lead to currency appreciation, making exports less competitive and harming long-term growth. Domestically, it may signal weak consumer demand and underinvestment in public services. Additionally, trading partners may view large surpluses as unfair, potentially provoking retaliatory measures. Therefore, while surpluses can be beneficial, their sustainability and impact depend on the broader economic context and balance with other objectives.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email